Political elections, appointment, analysis and visualization in Python
poli-sci-kit is a Python package for political science appointment and election analysis. The goal is to provide a comprehensive tool for all methods needed to analyze and simulate election results. See the documentation for a full outline of the package including algorithms and visualization techniques.
Contents
⇧
Installation poli-sci-kit can be downloaded from PyPI via pip or sourced directly from this repository:
pip install poli-sci-kit
git clone https://github.com/andrewtavis/poli-sci-kit.git
cd poli-sci-kit
python setup.py install
import poli_sci_kit
⇧
Appointment appointment.methods includes functions to allocate parliamentary seats based on population or vote shares. Included methods are:
Largest Remainder: Hare, Droop, Hagenbach–Bischoff (incl Hamilton, Vinton, Hare–Niemeyer)
Highest Averages: Jefferson, Webster, Huntington-Hill
Arguments to allow allocation thresholds, minimum allocations per group, tie break conditions, and other election features are also provided. Along with deriving results for visualization and reporting, these functions allow the user to analyze outcomes given systematic or situational changes. The appointment.metrics module further provides diagnostics to analyze the results of elections, apportionments, and other political science scenarios.
A basic example of political appointment using poli-sci-kit is:
from poli_sci_kit import appointment
vote_counts = [2700, 900, 3300, 1300, 2150, 500]
seats_to_allocate = 50
# Huntington-Hill is the method used to allocate House of Representatives seats to US states
ha_allocations = appointment.methods.highest_averages(
averaging_style="Huntington-Hill",
shares=vote_counts,
total_alloc=seats_to_allocate,
alloc_threshold=None,
min_alloc=1,
tie_break="majority",
majority_bonus=False,
modifier=None,
)
ha_allocations
# [26, 9, 37, 12, 23, 5]
# The Gallagher method is a measure of absolute difference similar to summing square residuals
disproportionality = appointment.metrics.dispr_index(
shares=vote_counts,
allocations=ha_allocations,
metric_type='Gallagher'
)
disproportionality
# 0.01002
We can also check that the allocations pass the quota condition:
passes_qc = appointment.checks.quota_condition(
shares=vote_counts,
seats=ha_allocations
)
passes_qc
# True
Allocation consistency can further be checked using dataframes of shares and seats given electoral settings. See appointment.checks and the documentation for explanations of method checks.
⇧
Plotting poli-sci-kit provides Python only implementations of common electoral plots.
Visualizing the above results:
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
import poli_sci_kit
# German political parties
parties = ['CDU/CSU', 'FDP', 'Greens', 'Die Linke', 'SPD', 'AfD']
party_colors = ['#000000', '#ffed00', '#64a12d', '#be3075', '#eb001f', '#009ee0']
Parliament Plots
poli_sci_kit provides implementations of both rectangular and semicircle parliament plots:
fig, (ax1, ax2) = plt.subplots(nrows=1, ncols=2)
ax1 = poli_sci_kit.plot.parliament(
allocations=seat_allocations,
labels=parties,
colors=party_colors,
style="rectangle",
num_rows=4,
marker_size=300,
speaker=True,
axis=ax1,
)
ax2 = poli_sci_kit.plot.parliament(
allocations=seat_allocations,
labels=parties,
colors=party_colors,
style="semicircle",
num_rows=4,
marker_size=175,
speaker=False,
axis=ax2,
)
plt.show()
Disproportionality Bar Plot
A novel addition to social science analysis is the disproportionality bar plot, which graphically depicts the disproportionality between expected and realized results. Bar widths are the proportion of shares (ex: votes received), and heights are the difference or relative difference between shares and allocations (ex: parliament seats received).
An example follows:
import pltviz
ax = poli_sci_kit.plot.dispr_bar(
shares=votes,
allocations=ha_allocations,
labels=parties,
colors=party_colors,
total_shares=None,
total_alloc=None,
percent=True,
axis=None,
)
handles, labels = pltviz.plot.legend.gen_elements(
counts=[round(v / sum(votes), 4) for v in votes],
labels=parties,
colors=party_colors,
size=11,
marker="o",
padding_indexes=None,
order=None,
)
ax.legend(
handles=handles,
labels=labels,
title="Vote Percents (bar widths)",
title_fontsize=15,
fontsize=11,
ncol=2,
loc="upper left",
bbox_to_anchor=(0, 1),
frameon=True,
facecolor="#FFFFFF",
framealpha=1,
)
ax.axes.set_title('Seat to Vote Share Disproportionality', fontsize=30)
ax.set_xlabel('Parties', fontsize=20)
ax.set_ylabel('Percent Shift', fontsize=20)
plt.show()
⇧
Examples Examples in poli-sci-kit use publicly available Wikidata statistics sourced via the Python package wikirepo. Current examples include:
-
- Allocates seats to a version of the US House of Representatives that includes all US territories and Washington DC given census data, with this further being used to derive relative vote strengths of state citizens in the US presidential election
-
- Analyzes the allocation of seats in a hypothetical global parliament given the prevalence of certain countries and organizations, the distribution of seats based on Freedom House indexes, as well as disproportionality metrics
⇧
To-Do Please see the contribution guidelines if you are interested in contributing to this project. Work that is in progress or could be implemented includes:
-
Adding the Adams method to appointment.methods.highest_averages (see issue)
-
Finishing accurate allocations in the semicircle variation of poli_sci_kit.plot.parliament (see issue)
-
Adding equations to appointment.methods docstrings for the documentation (see issue)
-
Deriving further needed arguments to assure that all current and historic appointment systems can be simulated using poli-sci-kit (see issue)
-
Potentially indexing preset versions of appointment.methods that coincide with the systems used by governments around the world
- This would allow quick comparisons of actual systems with variations
-
Creating, improving and sharing examples
-
Improving tests for greater code coverage
-
Improving code quality by refactoring large functions and checking conventions
References
Full list of references
-
Balinski, M. L., and Young, H. P. (1982). Fair Representation: Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote. New Haven, London: Yale University Press.
-
Karpov, A. (2008). "Measurement of disproportionality in proportional representation systems". Mathematical and Computer Modelling, Vol. 48, pp. 1421-1438. URL: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0895717708001933.
-
Kohler, U., and Zeh, J. (2012). “Apportionment methods”. The Stata Journal, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 375–392. URL: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/1536867X1201200303.
-
Taagepera, R., and Grofman, B. (2003). "Mapping the Indices of Seats-Votes Disproportionality and Inter-Election Volatility". Party Politics, Vol. 9, No. 6, pp. 659–677. URL: https://escholarship.org/content/qt0m9912ff/qt0m9912ff.pdf.